Japanese Foreign Direct Investment and Regional Trade

Tamim bayoumi and Gabrielle Lipworth

Finance and Development/September 1997


Japan's foreign direct investment abroad has boomed over the past decade as many Japanese companies have set up production facilities overseas. What impact has this had on Japan's manufacturing sector and trade patterns, and is it likely to continue?

Overview
What is driving FDI?
FDI and trade
Conclusion

Japanese investment in companies abroad has surged since the early 1980s, sparking debate on whether the Japanese economy is "hollowing out." Flows of foreign direct investment (FDI) from Japan to other countries have been much larger than the equivalent flows into Japan. This has aroused concerns that Japan's manufacturing base is being eroded as productive capacity is moving abroad, hurting domestic growth and employment.

The relocation of Japanese production abroad has also been connected to changes in Japan's trade structure. While short-term changes in trade volumes and prices are due largely to movements in relative prices and income, deeper underlying trends in Japan's current account may well reflect structural changes in exports and imports. Certainly, part of the decline in the trade balance from 1994 to mid-1996 appears to reflect the growth of exports of capital- and technology-intensive goods, and an increase in the share of manufactured goods in imports--and, in particular, an expansion of "reverse imports" from Japanese affiliates abroad.

Such trends raise a number of questions:

Overview

Three aspects of Japanese FDI since the early 1980s are particularly striking. First, outflows have exceeded inflows by more than a factor of 10--indeed, this gap has been growing. Second, outflows of Japanese FDI have shown a cyclical pattern that reflects movements in the yen as well as factors affecting activity in Japan and its major trading partners. Third, the sectoral and regional composition of FDI outflows have changed significantly.

Outbound Japanese FDI rose from 2.5 percent to 3 percent of domestic investment between 1982 and 1993 (prior to 1982, Japanese FDI was heavily regulated and hence not as subject to market forces), while inflows to Japan have remained approximately constant, at about 0.2 percent of Japan's domestic fixed investment. By 1993, the stock of Japanese FDI abroad stood at $422.5 billion--almost fifteen times the $29.9 billion stock of FDI received by Japan.

Outbound Japanese FDI has shown a cyclical pattern. In the first half of the 1980s, overseas investment increased briskly--in part to enable Japan to avoid trade frictions with Europe and North America in the automobile sector--to reach $12.2 billion in 1985 (around 1 percent of Japan's GDP). Growth accelerated further in the second half of the decade, most likely because of booming economies at home and abroad, and the appreciation of the yen. Japan's FDI outflows for 1986­89 surpassed the country's total overseas investment for the entire postwar period up to 1986. By the late 1980s, Japan was investing more abroad than any other country in the world, with its FDI peaking at $67.5 billion (around 2.5 percent of GDP) in 1989. This boom in Japanese FDI ended abruptly in the early 1990s when the asset-price bubble burst. For a few years, annual outflows declined steadily, both in absolute terms and relative to GDP and fixed investment, as the sharp decline in asset prices in 1990, which led to severe balance sheet difficulties for many businesses and banks, triggered a deep and protracted economic slump. More recently, FDI outflows have begun to recover, spurred by the appreciation of the yen in 1993­94 and the spring of 1995 and a pickup in domestic investment.
Coinciding with these cyclical movements have been notable changes in the regional and sectoral composition of outbound FDI. Japanese companies sharply increased their investment in North America in the 1980s. Indeed, during the 1980s, industrial countries saw their share of Japanese FDI grow to more than 75 percent of the total (the United States alone received 50 percent of total Japanese FDI), whereas developing countries (including those in Asia) saw their share drop from 50 percent to about 25 percent. During this period, Japanese overseas investment in the tertiary sectors--including finance, insurance, transport, and real estate--grew significantly, while the share of FDI in manufacturing and mining declined.
These trends have been partially reversed after the bursting of the asset-price bubble. The share of Japanese FDI received by developing countries has returned to the levels seen in the early 1980s--and the share received by Asian countries within this total has increased substantially. At the same time, FDI flows to industrial countries--particularly the United States --have decreased. The decline of Japanese investment in the United States coincided with the decline in Japanese investment in services, particularly real estate, while the corresponding increase in FDI outflows to other countries in Asia has led to increased Japanese foreign investment in manufacturing, particularly chemical products and machinery.

It is difficult to discern trends in the geographical composition of FDI inflows to Japan given the small size and "lumpy" nature of commitments (Chart 4). Flows from North America still account for the lion's share of FDI into Japan, although this share seems to have decreased from around 75 percent in the late 1980s to 50 percent in the early 1990s. Flows from Europe have fluctuated but appear to have risen slightly in the 1990s, while Asia's share has remained more or less constant at about 5 percent. Sectorally, there has been a decline in FDI inflows into the manufacturing sector in the 1990s, while investment in the service sector has gone up.

What is driving FDI?

The initial allocation of FDI flows across countries is normally determined by microeconomic factors, such as the desire to exploit economies of scale, penetrate foreign markets, or reap other benefits. Historically, for example, Japanese overseas investment during the postwar period has been concentrated in natural resource extraction and labor-intensive manufacturing. The former represents a form of backward vertical integration that has enabled Japanese companies in the traded goods sector to secure access to raw materials. Investment in manufacturing in neighboring Asian countries can also be seen in this light; it has allowed Japanese companies to move production abroad in a sector where Japan has been losing comparative advantage. More recently, increases in FDI have been associated with the rapid growth of spending on research and development by Japanese firms. Some Japanese FDI has also been triggered by policy actions that make it advisable to move production of certain goods to other countries. Trade frictions, for example, have stimulated flows of Japanese FDI to the United States and may have encouraged Japanese firms to invest in Asia so as to build "export platforms" for the US market.

While there is ample evidence in the academic literature of a link between FDI and economies of scale owing to the ownership of knowledge and policy-induced distortions, a microeconomic approach offers little insight into the cyclical volatility of FDI, nor can it adequately explain differences in FDI across countries that exhibit similar characteristics. For instance, foreign acquisitions in the United States fell by 60 percent in 1983 before more than doubling between 1986 and 1988, only to fall again by 30 percent between 1988 and 1990. Structural developments move too slowly to explain these changes. To understand FDI fluctuations, it is necessary to look at more short-term, cyclical factors, such as exchange rates, that affect costs and returns to investment.

While exchange rates can affect FDI in various ways, previous studies have generally found that a depreciation of the host country's currency has a positive effect on FDI inflows. A depreciation lowers the costs of production and investment in host countries relative to the cost in source countries, making foreign investment more profitable. The wealth effect is another channel through which a depreciation of the real exchange rate can boost FDI--by increasing the relative wealth of foreign firms, a depreciation of the real exchange rate can make it easier for those firms to use retained profits to finance investment abroad.

Our empirical analysis looked at FDI outflows between Japan and 20 of its major trading partners (Bayoumi and Lipworth, forthcoming). The results suggest that the main driving forces for Japanese FDI are domestic investment and the exchange rate, but that the investment climate of recipient countries influences the distribution of FDI.

The importance of domestic investment as a determinant of FDI is consistent with the view that Japanese FDI generally complements domestic production. Japanese FDI appears to be focused more on outsourcing than on providing an alternative location from which to supply foreign markets. Higher demand for Japanese goods leads to parallel increases in productive capacity at home and abroad. Thus, increases in domestic investment are associated with increases in FDI--a 3.5 percent increase in Japanese investment generates an increase in FDI of about 10 percent--while the impact of increases in host-country investment is much more muted. In contrast, if foreign subsidiaries were being established for the purpose of serving the local market in host countries--the purpose usually ascribed to FDI from the United States and other industrial countries--FDI would be more closely related to investment in the host country and domestic trends would be less relevant. Strikingly, there is no evidence that flows to low-wage Asian countries behave differently from flows to high-wage countries in North America and Europe, despite the fact that the sectoral composition of FDI differs across countries.

Changes in the value of the yen also have a strong influence on the behavior of Japanese FDI. In the short run, a 6 percent depreciation of the host country's currency vis-à-vis the yen would also generate an increase in FDI of roughly 10 percent. While Japan's total FDI has been driven mainly by domestic investment in Japan and fluctuations in the exchange rate, the geographic distribution of Japanese FDI has been influenced by economic conditions in recipient countries.

The short-term implication of these findings is that, although the depreciation of the yen since mid-1995 would normally have caused Japanese FDI to decrease, FDI is being stimulated by the growth of investment in Japan and in its partner countries, particularly in Asia. Overall, therefore, Japanese FDI is likely to continue to grow moderately over the next year or two.

FDI and trade

The shift of Japanese production abroad has stimulated imports from overseas affiliates; in particular, the share of manufactured goods in total imports has grown. Our analysis indicates that a higher stock of Japanese FDI has permanently affected imports--between 1990 and 1995, outward FDI may have increased merchandise imports by around 10 percent.

The relationship between FDI and exports is more complex. Our analysis shows that FDI flows have a significant impact on exports but that the stock of FDI has no significant effect. In other words, FDI has only a temporary impact on Japanese exports--plausibly because new facilities set up by Japanese firms are often equipped using capital goods from Japan. Once production overseas is on track, however, the finished products that were once exported from Japan will be manufactured overseas. It is difficult to determine a priori whether FDI results in a long-term rise or fall in total exports, but the impact of FDI on the export structure is more clear-cut--exports of capital goods rise and exports of consumer goods decline. And, of course, exports from firms located abroad increase as their production increases.

Conclusion

Japanese firms are diversifying the location of their production and moving to other countries those parts of their operations in which they are losing comparative advantage. While the recent depreciation of the yen is likely to temper this process, Japanese FDI outflows are part of a necessary restructuring of the Japanese economy, reflecting globalization and economic growth in the rest of Asia. Despite the pain involved, such a restructuring will produce a domestic economy better able to face the rigors of the world economy in the future.

Tamim Bayoumi,
a British national, is a Senior Economist in the IMF's Asia and Pacific Department.
Gabrielle Lipworth,
a South African national, is an Economist in the IMF's Asia and Pacific Department.

This article is based on the authors' paper, "Japanese Foreign Direct Investment and Regional Trade," which is forthcoming in the IMF's Working Paper series.