3. Assessing the impact and potential of EPZs in a global economy

Are zones effective?

Most zone-operating countries consider two issues when assessing the efficacy of zones, namely:

To these they often add a third:

The data presented in Chapter 2 of this report indicate that many zones have indeed succeeded in attracting significant amounts of investment in labour-intensive industries with the result that large numbers of jobs have been created. For those labour-surplus economies concerned solely with the quantity of employment the assessment need not go any further, but many zone-operating countries have started to pose questions about the quality of that investment and the jobs created. The generosity of the investment incentives, the peculiarities of the Multifibre Arrangement and the growth of subcontracting resulted in many zones attracting small- and medium-scale investments of a very expedient nature. Such investment does not bring with it a longer-term commitment to the host country, and the enterprises involved seek their comparative advantage in reduced costs of production rather than through improvements in productivity. Many zones have consequently not managed to attract the quality of investment and jobs that they had hoped for and are now considering ways to upgrade them.

In a number of zone-operating countries, however, the objectives of the zone strategy go a lot further than the quantity of investment and employment. They hope to use foreign investment in the export sector to promote broader economic development and higher standards of living through:

When measured against these broader economic, social and labour objectives the results of the zone strategy are mixed. The host government spends large amounts of money on the infrastructure, maintenance and running costs of the zones, and may well have to upgrade the facilities at a later stage. To that expense must be added the opportunity cost which includes not only the lost earnings from taxes and duties but the diversion of resources from other developmental activities. In return the country attracts investors, collects rents, boosts exports, generates foreign exchange and creates jobs. Zone investors increase demand for local goods and services, particularly in the energy, construction, transport and packaging sectors, and zone workers have some spending power which benefits local suppliers of accommodation, transport and consumer goods. However, the positive impact of these factors has been limited for the following reasons:

This consideration of the costs and benefits of a zone strategy raises a number of important questions. How can zone-operating countries ensure that the quality of zone investment improves, and that it has knock-on effects in terms of broader social and economic development? The answer may lie in changing the definition of EPZs.